Externality and Inequality
by Sinclair Noe
DOW
+ 45 = 12,588
SPX + 6 = 1359
NAS + 16 = 2853
10 YR YLD -.02 = 1.57%
OIL + 1.05 = 86.50
GOLD – 2.40 = 1714.70
SILV - .29 = 32.41
SPX + 6 = 1359
NAS + 16 = 2853
10 YR YLD -.02 = 1.57%
OIL + 1.05 = 86.50
GOLD – 2.40 = 1714.70
SILV - .29 = 32.41
Top
Congressional leaders met with President Obama today at the White
House. Democrats said they recognized the need to curb spending.
Republicans said they agreed to put revenue on the table. They sang a
chorus of Kumbaya; they left the meeting and talked to the press.
Mitch McConnell, John Boehner, Nancy Pelosi and Harry Reid all shared
the microphone; both sides pledged cooperation; both sides agreed
that driving over the fiscal cliff was a big bucket of crazy; no
blood was shed today. Don't hold your breath.
Former
Federal Reserve Chairman Alan “Bubbles” Greenspan says allowing
taxes to rise would be a small price to pay to get lawmakers to
accept spending cuts on entitlement programs, even if it leads to a
moderate recession. So, what is on the negotiating table is starting
to emerge, even though the goal posts are still moving targets. What
is most interesting at this point is not the proposals that are on
the table but the proposals that never make it to the table. How
can we really have a debt to GDP ratio problem when we have a
non-convertible fiat currency, a floating exchange rate and debts in
currencies not our own? Yea, that isn't going to be part of the
discussion.
And
that brings us to today's main topic: externalities and inequality.
You
may have noticed that the markets don't always produce the best
possible social outcomes. The pollution generated by a factory
imposes costs on those who live downstream or in the path of its
airborne emissions. The risks assumed by banks leading up to the
recent financial crisis imposed costs on just about everybody. Market
transactions often generate “externalities”, or side effects,
sometimes positive but often negative, that affect people who do not
participate in the transaction. What's the solution?
Well if you want less of something you tax it. You could tax the
negative externalities and subsidize the positive externalities.
Does
the fact that hedge-fund manager rakes in 100 or 1,000 times what
office manager earns impose costs on everybody else? Plenty of
Americans think not. Defenders of our income inequality point out
that a free-enterprise system requires some inequality.
Unequal rewards give people an incentive to work hard and acquire new
skills. They encourage inventors to invent, entrepreneurs to start
companies, investors to take risks. It’s fine in this view that
some people get astronomically rich.
On
the other side, many of us have a gut feeling that inequality has
gone too far. Our times are reminiscent of the Gilded Age’s worst
excesses.
The
conventional strategy for fighting inequality is to tax the rich. The
idea is based on a foundation of fairness, and the question of what’s
fair and what’s unfair turns out to cut different ways, depending
on your point of view. You may find it unfair that the very rich take
in so much more than others. Somebody else might wonder why the rich
should be taxed so heavily. Don’t they already pay
disproportionately more than everyone else? These arguments hit a
dead end. So, the lemming politicians are ready to run off a fiscal
cliff over marginal top tax rates of 35% or 39%, that have already
demonstrated negligible effects in reducing inequality. No one even
discusses top rates that might make a difference. So
what we need to look at is how skewed income distribution imposes
costs on the rest of us.
Between
the end of World War II and 1973, the top marginal tax rate never
dropped below 70%, and for a while it was more than 90%, and growth
in real domestic product per capita averaged close to 2.5%; in other
words: Good Times. Since the the economy has continued to grow, an
average of about 2.1%, but the median household income has only
increased 0.4%. The average income of the top 1% has increased more
than 300% but the median household income has increased by less than
20%. From
1975 to 2008, the median household income rose by a total of $8,000
(in today’s dollars). Had the distribution remained the same as it
was in the postwar years, the increase would have been $40,000.
Instead of its current level, $50,000, the median income of US
households today would be $86,400. So, that might be considered a
real dollar cost.
Also,
there is the cost of people who focus narrowly on getting richer.
For young people, going where the money is becomes more attractive
than a career in science, education, or public service. As late as
1986, only 18 percent of Harvard graduates planned any sort of
business career. In 2011, the figure was 41 percent, including 17
percent going into finance.
The
new incentives affect the behavior of anyone with a decent shot at
getting rich. CEOs of large corporations expect astronomical
compensation packages. Wall Street executives pursue riskier lines
of business in search of higher profits than they could earn through
traditional banking or brokerage; and if they commit fraud, they pay
a partial fine and move on to their next risky venture. Doctors and
lawyers have an incentive to train for lucrative subspecialties,
leaving a shortage of general practitioners and public defenders. All
these brain drains and unnecessary risks impose costs on everyone
else.
There
is yet another cost to democracy. Despite fundamental principles such
as one person, one vote, the wealthiest Americans have always wielded
disproportionate political influence, but with Buckley v. Vallejo and
Citizens United, the courts have granted personhood to corporations
and ruled that money is speech not property. The result is
politicians are bought and paid for, or at the very least, influenced
by legions of lobbyists.
Little
wonder, then, that disaffected citizens on the right, on the left,
and in the middle; whatever their views on inequality, believe that
the very rich and organized business interests have hijacked
America’s political process. Sustained economic growth depends on
open and inclusive political institutions.
Based
on the examples it appears that a highly skewed income distribution
results in negative political externalities. The most evident
solution? Slap a tax on vastly unequal incomes, and watch the
externalities shrink. Then we must ask the question “why” this
is a viable solution. First, its purpose is to reduce
inequality, not to
make everyone pay a “fair share.” This goal cuts through the
complaint that the rich are already paying far more than their share
in taxes. Second, the tax should seek to change incentives. That is,
its goal is to alter the pretax
distribution
of income, not just the after-tax distribution, to discourage people
from seeking to earn exponentially more than their fellow citizens.
With higher tax rates, a job in finance might lose some of its appeal
to talented young people. CEOs might be happy with salaries averaging
20 times the typical worker’s earnings (the ratio in 1965) instead
of 351 times the average, as was the case in 2007.
Finally,
a tax on externalities is not designed to stop activity; a tax on
pollution is not designed to eliminate industrial production, and a
tax on inequality is not designed to equalize outcomes. It seeks only
to reduce inequality from a level that threatens democracy to a level
compatible with democracy, while still encouraging plenty of work and
innovation. There would still be super-rich Americans, just not as
many; some of them would be merely rich. And remember that after
World War II top tax rates never dropped below 70% and the economy
posted the strongest quarter-century of growth in its history. And we
know that inequality increases when the top tax rates fall.
It
might be argued that this only shows a correlation not causation; and
that is possible. So, you might argue that high marginal tax rates
are a threat to overall economic growth, but that argument doesn't
hold up. There simply is no correlation; the economy grows more with
higher marginal tax rates. How is this possible?
In
every economy there are positive-sum games, in which market
interactions benefit both parties, and zero-sum games, in which one
party loses and the other wins. In a positive sum equation, we know
the rich don't produce 351 times more widgets than the average
worker. The answer is found in zero-sum activities, where the gains
come at somebody else's loss. Zero-sum actions include increasing
corporate earnings by holding down wages, taking advantage of
financial customers by creating and gambling on complex or risky
products that customers don’t understand, and lobbying Congress for
protection from competition. As these examples suggest, some
individuals in the top income group pursue quite a number of
activities that others might be glad to see them spending less time
on.
The
lack of any limit to outsize economic rewards turns out to have a
measurable cost, which Americans who aren’t so wealthy keep getting
asked to pay. The way to change this is to recognize the
externalities exist and to shift the incentives.
Yesterday we talked about the big settlement BP reached with the Department of Justice and the SEC over criminal charges related to the Deepwater Horizon oil rig explosion and spill of a couple years ago. One day later, and there is a new oil rig explosion in the Gulf of Mexico. It appears that 2 people are missing and 4 people have been evacuated; there were unconfirmed reports that 2 people died. The fire has been extinguished. The oil rig is run by a company called Black Elk. They've been fined for safety violations within the past year. The CEO of Black Elk used to work for BP.
JPMorgan
and Credit Suisse have reached settlements with the SEC over civil
charges that they fraudulently misled investors in residential
mortgage backed securities. JPMorgan
will pay $296 million, while Credit Suisse will pay $120 million.
Both agreed to settle without admitting or denying the charges.
The
SEC accused JPMorgan of making materially false and misleading
statements about the quality of home loans that backed a $1.8 billion
residential mortgage-backed securities (RMBS) offering it underwrote
in December 2006. It also held JPMorgan responsible for the failure
of Bear Stearns Cos, which the bank bought in 2008, to disclose its
practice of keeping cash settlements from loan originators on problem
loans that Bear sold into mortgage loan trusts.
Credit
Suisse failed to disclose similar cash settlements, and also made
misstatements in regulatory filings about when it would buy back
mortgage loans when borrowers missed their first payments, known as
first payment defaults.
Earlier
this week, we learned the euro-zone has relapsed into double-dip
recession as the austerity shock in the Mediterranean region spreads
to the core countries of the north. The Club Med countries had a
debilitating jolt of austerity without the juice of stimulus and the
result has been contraction across the entire euro-zone. Unemployment
across the EU has hit a record high 11.6%, and GDP has turned
negative everywhere except Germany and France; give them time. I
imagine Greenspan would find this acceptable, but its not real
popular in Athens or Madrid. Even the International Monetary Fund
looked at the past few years of harsh austerity and concluded that
contractionary policies are contractionary
Palestinian
missiles landed in areas around Jerusalem and Tel Aviv. Israel
extended its bombing of the Gaza Strip and took steps to escalate.
Israeli prime Minister Netanyahu is talking about calling up 75,000
reservists, which could signal a ground incursion into Gaza. About
550 rockets have been fired into Israel over the past two days, with
197 intercepted by their missile defense system. Israeli air strikes
have hit more than 600 targets in Gaza. Israel’s air strikes have
eliminated most of the long-range missiles in Gaza but there is still
a threat. Israel said yesterday that it’s ready to step up its
operation if rocket fire continues.
Maybe
the Mayans were right.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.